A great many colleges give preference in admission to children of alumni. (This includes public colleges because few colleges any more rely entirely on public funding.) It is widely believed, with some evidence, that alumni give more generously to their alma mater if their children are admitted to, and especially if, having been admitted, they attend, the college that they (the alumni) attended. This is the passionate belief of admissions officer, and if it were false it would have been abandoned, because it attracts a good deal of criticism.
The “legacy” preference is not a mere tie breaker; as in the case of preferences for blacks, Hispanics, and athletes, it amounts in effect to pretending that the applicant had a substantially higher score on the Scholastic Aptitude Test than he or she actually had.
The preferences for blacks and Hispanics are defended on the ground (possibly spurious in most cases, reflecting pressure from government rather than educational theory) that they are better than their high-school records or SAT scores suggest, because of a disadvantaged upbringing; in fact the colleges, at least the elite ones, try to admit the nondisadvantaged members of these minorities because they are more likely to graduate. But the athletic and legacy preferences have strictly financial motivations. Alumni donations amount to some 28 percent of total college revenues, and both athletic prowess and admission of alumni offspring are considered important to alumni donations.
The practice of favoring alumni children seems to be particularly strong in elite colleges, though statistics are hard to come by because most colleges will not reveal the admission rate of alumni children relative to the admission rate for applicants who do not belong to preferred minorities, are not good athletes, and are not alumni children. Not that such statistics would be meaningful by themselves, at least in the case of alumni children admitted to elite schools. By definition one of the parents attended such a school, namely the one their child has applied to; and given assortative matching in marriage, there is a good chance that the other parent went to the same, or another, elite school, as well. Hence their children are probably of above-average quality (unless their parents were second- or third-generation legacy admits), in which event they would be admitted at a higher rate than non-legacy applicants even without legacy preference. What one needs to know is how great the preference for alumni children is and therefore how many are admitted who wouldn’t be without the preference. We don’t know how great it is, but it must be significant; otherwise colleges wouldn’t bother to give the preference—most alumni children would be admitted without it.
Admitting an applicant to an elite college because one or both of his parents went there is offensive in a nation whose constitution forbids the granting of titles of nobility. It confers an arbitrary advantage, based on ancestry rather than on merit or promise. The advantage is not primarily that the preferentially admitted student receives a better education; he may not, because the fact that he would not have been admitted without a preference suggests that he may not be a motivated or talented student; and you cannot make silk purses out of sow’s ears. But his degree from an elite college will open doors; prospective employers, even if they discover that an applicant is the child of an alumnus of the college he attended, will not know whether he was one of the alumni children who wouldn’t have been admitted had it not been for the connection. The student will also derive social benefits (prestige, maybe some extra refinement) and valuable contacts from hobnobbing with the other students; elite colleges have a disproportionate number of elite students.
The same argument is made against allowing gifts and bequests by wealthy parents (or, more realistically, against light or no taxation of such transfers): that they confer an arbitrary advantage. It is further argued that they blunt the children’s ambition. But there are counterarguments, which cumulatively are compelling: heavy taxation of gifts and bequests increases consumption at the expense of investment; reduces parents’ utility and their incentive to work hard; weakens family bonds; and reduces constructive risk taking by young people by reducing the number of young people who have financial security. Abandoning legacy admissions would have much smaller effects. The major one would be a reduction in alumni giving, and no one knows how much of a reduction there would be, or the extent to which it could be offset by more vigorous solicitation of alumni donations. But the benefits from abolishing legacy admissions would also be slight, if I am right that one of the principal benefits to the legatees is social—the benefits from rubbing shoulders with elite students. For the students whom the alumni children displace at the elite schools still go to college. They just will drop down a notch in the college pecking order; and their presence in colleges at that level will be a boon to the other students in those colleges.
Furthermore, if one asks who exactly will replace the alumni children if legacy admissions disappear, the answer—better qualified students—must itself be qualified by recognition that parents invest money to improve their children’s college admission prospects, and their investment may enable a somewhat less able applicant to be admitted in preference to an abler one. The parents may have financed a highly expensive elementary and high school education for their children at an elite private school, hired tutors for them, and financed extracurricular activites of the kind that impress admissions officers. The greater the inequality of income in the society—and it is very great in our society at present—the more that wealthy people will be able to gain access to elite colleges for their children, and by doing so underwrite the children’s future economic success and social prestige.
This point suggests that, as long as colleges are private (including de facto private, which is increasingly the case with public colleges, many of which like the University of Michigan, receive only a small fraction of their money from the state), they will follow a business model, and a business model of education is inherently tilted in favor of applicants who may not be the most promising students, whether they are members of preferred minorities, athletes, children of very wealthy people even if neither parent is an alumnus (such children are favored by many colleges), children with an impressive resume attributable to a significant effect in their parents’ investment in them, or alumni children. Although most colleges—and all elite colleges—are nonprofit institutions, the only difference between most nonprofit institutions and for-profit institutions is that the former cannot distribute surplus revenue (profit) to the people who supply them with capital: there are no shareholders or dividends. They are no less competitive than private institutions. One can imagine a system in which all education, from kindergarten to graduate and professional school, would be financed by the government, but few would argue that such a system would be an improvement over what we have, even though what we have has many unattractive features.
The ultimate question from an economic standpoint is whether legacy admissions create a harmful externality, which is to say impose a cost on society that the parties to the practice that causes the externality do not take into account. The college and its legacy admits like the practice of legacy admissions and do not want to change it; should they be forced to because of the harm the practice causes to other members of society?
I think not. The harms are of two kinds. First, legacy admissions undermine the matching of the best students with the best colleges. That kind of “assortative mating” is probably most efficient from the standpoint of maximizing the gains from education; and education creates benefits for society as a whole. With legacy admissions, there are fewer places for the best students in the best colleges; some of those best are relegated to the next tier of colleges. On the other hand, students learn from other students as well as from teachers, and those “best” who are knocked down a tier thus benefit their fellow students in the second-tier colleges to which they are admitted. The net loss to educational efficiency caused by legacy may well be slight—it may even be negative if abolition of legacies would result in a significant reduction in alumni donations and therefore in college resources.
Second, legacy admissions increase inequality, or at least may increase it (this qualification is explained below). Inequality, beyond a point we may have reached, is harmful to society as a whole; the enormous federal deficit is in part a result of efforts by the Bush Administration as well as the Obama Administration to offset wage stagnation and rsulting increased inequality by heavy borrowing to fund entitlement programs. But the increase in inequality brought about by legacy admissions is probably infinitesimal. Moreover, legacy admissions may actually reduce inequality, because the abler person pushed down to a lower-tier school may have lower lifetime earnings as a result, and if as is likely he is upper middle class, the reduction in his lifetime earnings will reduce inequality.
I continue to find the practice distasteful. But I don’t think public intervention (which might take the form of federal and state regulations conditioning financial assistance to colleges on the abandonment of the practice) is warranted.
"students learn from other students as well as from teachers, and those “best” who are knocked down a tier thus benefit their fellow students in the second-tier colleges to which they are admitted."
Charming. When you read such nonsense from a federal judge, you can imagine the insane rationalizations that judges employ in their day-to-day decision-making involving "diadvantaged" litigants.
Posted by: Harris Don | 06/05/2011 at 08:28 PM
Just another case where getting the gummint the hell out would improve the situation. When the gummint takes over health care and grocery stores, I expect Posner to make his usual specious analysis and justification of the inequities.
Posted by: Jimbino | 06/05/2011 at 09:00 PM
Two questions:
1) The only defense for race-based admissions is that black or latino students "are better than their high-school records or SAT scores suggest, because of a disadvantaged upbringing"? What about the value of having a student body from diverse backgrounds because being able to look at issues from different perspectives is vital to the learning process? After all, you do say "students learn from other students as well as from teachers" in the second-to-last paragraph.
2) The problem with inequality is the result of the federal government's deficit spending over the past two administrations? What does that have to do with the fact that, from 1980-2005, more than 80% of total increase in Americans' income went to the top 1%?
http://web.mit.edu/ipc/publications/pdf/07-002.pdf
Is there any way to argue that legacy admissions don't reinforce and solidify these gross disparities in wealth and income? The answer is not this:
"legacy admissions may actually reduce inequality, because the abler person pushed down to a lower-tier school may have lower lifetime earnings as a result, and if as is likely he is upper middle class, the reduction in his lifetime earnings will reduce inequality."
The "abler person" may be from an upper middle class family (say, top 10-15% of society), but is obviously not sufficiently well-heeled to have his/her parents buy his/her admission to the elite college. Disadvantaging the person from the top 12% in favor of the person from the top 0.5% is not reducing inequality.
Posted by: boo | 06/05/2011 at 10:39 PM
Legacy admissions are an unambiguous assault on meritocracy. This is so regardless of the fact that the business models of elite institutions rely on them.
Posted by: Philip Rothman | 06/06/2011 at 01:06 AM
The main dispute I have with this argument is the proposition that bumping smarter students down a tier increases the efficiency of the system. In many areas, classes run most efficiently when most of the students are in a relatively tight intellectual band. Classes where there are too many "smarter students" move too quickly to effectively educate the rest. Conversely, classes that have many (or even a couple, if they participate extensively) slower learners end up moving at a pace that is inefficient for those who have extra learning capacity. This is the reason high schools have tracks (e.g. honors, college prep, standard, special needs), and these tracks are efficient.
I agree with Posner that the benefits of the system probably outweigh the costs. However, I don't believe that decreasing the homogenization of intellectual ability within a particular college, class, etc. has benefits that outweigh the educational costs.
Posted by: Mario Lucero | 06/06/2011 at 07:46 AM
Some critics of college admissions processes have noted that from the college-bound pool of applicants, many colleges might be better off admitting candidates at random, rather than creating a high level of selectivity by looking at diversity, academics, athletics, community service, and other invented critieria. The real test is not always whether someone gets in but whether they can stay in a particular university past freshman year. The invention of the SAT was to establish a process to break open the closed nature of elite universities and to, at least, provide a leading indicator of possible performance and enhance a meritocratic approach to university admissions. Admissions officers who ignore the SAT are taking us back a century.
A more onerous practice that also helps 'legacy' matriculants is the "Gentleman's C" which still exists and not just for athletes. It would be also possible to weigh in on 'low-challenge' EasyA classes.
Posted by: Jim Houston | 06/06/2011 at 10:28 AM
I see nothing wrong with a little nepotism, provided the individual in question can cut the muster and carry their own load creditably.
However, I have problems with it if it denies me a place or becomes a barrier to my own ambitions and advancement. The same applies to the issues of race, gender or creed.
Fairness in admissions? Who said the world is fair. Give me a break. Equity is not the issue, never has been...
Posted by: NEH | 06/06/2011 at 02:59 PM
Every dog has his day.
Posted by: Supra Strapped NS | 06/07/2011 at 01:23 AM
Both of these articles engage in a false comparison. Implicitly, each article compares between colleges voluntarily having legacy admission standards and colleges voluntarily doing away with legacy admission standards. The real choice is between colleges having legacy admission standards and a group of government employees deciding what the colleges' admission standards will be. Both articles are filled with discussions of what the colleges incentives are, but none on what the governmental regulator's incentives would be. This is disappointingly naive for two authors of such high repute. Did they miss the whole public choice school?
Max
Posted by: Maximize Liberty | 06/07/2011 at 01:22 PM
Posner writes that "one can imagine a system in which all education, from kindergarten to graduate and professional school, would be financed by the government."
One need not imagine such a system. Government-subsidized lending to college students is pervasive. Add the panoply of junky tax credits and deductions that likewise subsidize higher education, and there is no doubt we have such a system today.
Posted by: TANSTAAFL | 06/07/2011 at 08:40 PM
Nice Tips! thanks for the sharing....
Posted by: twin screw extruder | 06/08/2011 at 01:48 AM
Thanks for sharing these nice tips.You are doing a fine job.Keep up the great work.
Posted by: Custom Logo Design | 06/08/2011 at 01:51 AM
People often say things like "just because I find the practice repuganant, doesn't mean I think it should be banned." (And in this vein, Judge Posner leaves out the costs of enforcement.)
Here I think the reverse is true. Okay, fine, legacy admissions shouldn't be banned. Is the Judge just going to leave it at that? Isn't there another decision to be made -- namely, whether a particular institution should have this policy in the first place? A strong statement against legacy admissions from someone of Judge Posner's stature would likely have a lot of influnce, at least at the University of Chicago. (And the U of Chicago ending the practice would in turn be influential throughout America.) As it stands now, Judge Posner has done little more than knock down a straw man argument.
Posted by: James | 06/08/2011 at 04:59 PM
It does not take much reflection to see the kinship between legacy admissions and tuition discounts for in-state students at public colleges. The usual crowd that shouts about inequality, and decries practices like legacy admissions, seeks the elimination of all distinctions in admitting students to colleges. That might be fine if they sought to preserve distinctions based on academic merit, but that is not their true aim. Such folks want the equality of admissions that typified the Soviet Union. Ugh.
Posted by: TANSTAAFL | 06/08/2011 at 08:40 PM
the "legacy" system was responsible for Bush 43 having sufficient credentials to be elected president
is any more evidence needed of how bad an idea false credentialing happens to be
Only Clarence Thomas endorses the "legacy" system, but he can sense the stigma from affirmative action
Posted by: an observer | 06/08/2011 at 08:55 PM
Your site appeared to be pretty beneficial. I have already been looking through your website a lot within the last day or two and it has received an area at my favorites. thanks.
Posted by: florence | 06/09/2011 at 03:02 AM
That's a pretty good post!
Posted by: denis | 06/09/2011 at 09:20 PM
wow, awesome article! I agree with your point!
Posted by: david | 06/09/2011 at 09:22 PM
The perception that college education is essential for success and happiness has led to the fact that this is something everyone wants or needs, the universities becoming major businesses, driving the costs up for a whole variety of reasons, giving the pols the opportunity to "provide" (in exchange for votes) and the consequential federal and state control. Legacies cannot be far from doom unless of course one can can somehow "influence" someone. Think health care become education
Posted by: Jim | 06/10/2011 at 09:39 AM
Boo raises two interesting points. The first is the claim that racial/ethnic diversity brings different points of view to the classroom, thereby stimulating deeper discussion and thought. I do not see this kind of dynamic actually occurring very often on American college campuses. In fact, speech codes and PC make it next to impossible to discuss controversial topics centered on race/ethnicity/language/culture. This trend goes hand-in-hand with the near monopoly the left has on college faculty.
A further problem here is that racial/cultural differences are not simply intellectual. Rather, these differences give rise to subtle unconscious differences that are next to impossible to fully recognize and to bridge. Many philosophical differences are rooted in different ways of life. The intellectual aspects of various conflicts are the tip of an iceberg that are largely tacit.
The second point Boo raises centers on equality of result. I agree that it is not only ineffectual to relegate the more talented students to second-tier schools, but I am shocked that Judge Posner would see hindering the development of the more talented for the sake of what is likely to be the source of the demand for greater equality, and that is resentful envy. Of course, it is another matter altogether whether top-tier schools offer a better education. I doubt that most do.
Posted by: Christopher Graves | 06/12/2011 at 07:24 AM
"Moreover, legacy admissions may actually reduce inequality, because the abler person pushed down to a lower-tier school may have lower lifetime earnings as a result, and if as is likely he is upper middle class, the reduction in his lifetime earnings will reduce inequality."
Creating circumstances under which talented individuals do worse than they would have if US colleges did not have a legacy preference might in fact reduce inequality. Making artificial barriers for best and brightest will push them down a little. But is that really how we want to achieve greater equality?
Posted by: Robert Kwasny | 06/12/2011 at 10:58 AM
Hmm..Nice... like this share.. :)
Posted by: hybrid cars | 06/12/2011 at 11:33 AM
"The “legacy” preference is not a mere tie breaker; as in the case of preferences for blacks, Hispanics, and athletes, it amounts in effect to pretending that the applicant had a substantially higher score on the Scholastic Aptitude Test than he or she actually had."
That is actually exactly how preferences for blacks, Hispanics, and athletes work. If anything, being a black/Hispanic/athlete helps more than being a legacy.
Posted by: Mike | 06/14/2011 at 11:50 AM
Add the panoply of junky tax credits and deductions that likewise subsidize higher education, and there is no doubt we have such a system today.
Posted by: eBridge advertising | 06/23/2011 at 09:11 AM
The major one would be a reduction in alumni giving, and no one knows how much of a reduction there would be, or the extent to which it could be offset by more vigorous solicitation of alumni donations.
Posted by: cash for phone | 07/01/2011 at 02:15 AM