No, no breathrough. It’s true that earlier this week the White House released its “National Drug Control Strategy 2013,” heralded in some quarters as a breakthrough in national drug control strategy because it calls drug addiction a disease and promises to devote a higher percentage of federal drug control funds to treatment and prevention of drug abuse than in previous years. But a solid majority of federal drug control funds (58 percent) will continue to be devoted to the enforcement of the federal criminal laws, with their savage sentences, against participants in illegal-drug markets.
The publication of a White House “National Drug Control Strategy” is an annual event, which wordily (the 2013 version is 95 pages long) heralds nonexistent progress and makes false promises of more to come. The General Accountability Office has evaluated the 2013 version and found it wanting, noting the government’s lack of progress toward achieviing the goals of diminished drug use stated in the 2010 version.
The new (that is, the ostensibly new) strategy gives continued primacy to the “war on drugs,” which best describes the criminal-law and (abroad) paramilitary campaigns against the drug trade. No one thinks these campaigns can eradicate illegal drugs. The realistic-seeming objective is, by increasing expected punishment cost and by taking out of circulation (through imprisonment) those not deterred by the cost, the war on drugs raises the prices of illegal drugs. Yet those prices remain very low. The reason appears to be the very high elasticity of supply of drug dealers. It’s like Karl Marx’s “reserve army of the unemployed”; if there is no dearth of persons willing to be drug dealers at modest wages, the principal effect of law enforcement may be to increase labor turnover, at enormous cost in police and prosecutorial resources and above all in incarceration: half the federal prison population in the United States consists of drug offenders. Some 1.7 million persons who are in prison or jail (state or federal) or on probation or parole (or its federal equivalent, supervised release) are in those situations of confinement or restriction because of drug offenses. No doubt the mere fact that drugs are illegal deters some consumers—but how many relative to the large number of persons who have no interest in consuming mind-altering drugs, legal or illegal?
Increasingly the war on drugs seems an expensive failure. But treatment and prevention (prevention other than through the threat or actuality of imprisonment) are no panaceas. There are several problems. The first is the difficulty of distinguishing between harmful and harmless use of drugs. Much of the consumption of illegal drugs is either not harmful to the user at all, or is no more harmful than the legal substitutes (such as cigarettes and alcoholic beverages) to which consumers of mind-alterating drugs would be likely to turn if the illegal drugs were unavailable or very expensive. It would be foolish to break a person of his cocaine habit only to see him become an alcoholic.
Furthermore, not all drug users are addicts; and not all addictions are harmful. Much behavior is habitual, yet harmless; “addiction” is simply a pejorative term for habitual behavior.
No doubt much drug use is harmful to the user. But trying to prevent self-destructive behavior (at least by adults) is problematic. It not only is often very difficult to identify such behavior, but unless it imposes external costs it is a questionable object of government attention. One person’s self-destructive behavior is another person’s greatest pleasure in life. And therefore people generally are allowed to engage in self-destructive behavior, whether playing football, hang gliding, mountain climbing, smoking cigarettes, or drinking sugared soft drinks. Forcing people to be healthy is not a feasible goal of public policy—especially forcing people to avoid just one type of unhealthful habit, thus inviting them to switch to an unhealthful habit that happens to be lawful. There are externalities to self-destructive behavior, but often they can be curbed by withholding public benefits. For example, a person disabled from working by drug addiction is ineligible for social security diability benefits.
“Prevention” and “treatment” sound good, especially in contrast to “prosecution” and “imprisonment.” But there is a serious question of efficacy. I don’t know how feasible it is to break people of a drug habit, but suppose it’s quite feasible. Even so, unless they had become addicts accidentally, they are likely to become re-addicted once their treatment is complete. They will become re-addicted for the same reason they became addicted in the first place. They will be like the countless overweight people who go on diet after diet yet never achieve a lasting loss of weight.
It’s been noted disapprovingly that the 2013 White House strategy report does not mention the legalization of recreational (as distinct from just medicinal) use of marijuana by the states of Colorado and Washington. On the contrary, the strategy announces ambitious though probably Quixotic plans to extirpate the growing of marijuana in the United States. (How could that be achieved? Marijuana can be grown in one’s garden, or for that matter indoors. No importation or manufacture is required.)
Of course a state cannot preempt a federal law. But wouldn’t an ideal experiment for the federal government to conduct be to suspend enforcement of federal marijuana laws in Colorado and Washington (except to forbid the export of marijuana from those states to other states) and see what the consequences were? And if it turned out that the health consequences were nil, wouldn’t that point to the possible repeal of the laws nationwide? Anyway, if Colorado and Washington want to allow recreational use of marijuana by its citizens, why should the federal government care?
Note finally that decriminalization could be coupled with excise taxation to make illegal drugs, like legal alcohol and cigarettes, a source of badly needed government revenues. Decriminalization coupled with taxation might well be a superior alternative to prohibition. As with liquor, drug use by children would continue to be prohibited and heavy punishments would be imposed on dealers who sold to children.
With Mercedes releasing the first mass-produced self-driving car this year, it will probably be only another fifteen years or so before technology will have eliminated the threat of impaired driving.
Overall criminality is surely increased by the criminalization of drugs, but suppose people have varying degrees of anti-social propensity. Is the anti-socialness of the general population decreased when we incarcerate drug offenders? Maybe, but on the other hand people are probably a lot more anti-social after prison than they are when they go in, so the effect may run the other way. And anyway, locking up drug users because they might be slightly more inclined toward other bad behavior is an inefficient (and spooky) way to improve society!
Posted by: Kevinfrei.blogspot.com | 05/05/2013 at 03:05 PM
There has been a lot of drug prevention campaign rolled out in the past. But still drug addiction remains to be a menace to the society. Personal injury cases continue to increase because of reckless driving by a driver under the influence of alcohol and drugs.
Posted by: Glenn Law | 06/21/2013 at 02:45 PM
I just had a quick question regarding illegal drug and activities that might tie into this article. Although printing more money creates inflation, does the illegal printing and transfer of money contribute to the inflation rate, and or GDP overall?
Posted by: Nikhil Bhat | 07/08/2013 at 03:00 PM